Arabic symbol

 

 

 

 

Welcome Who We Philosophers Research Discourse News Services

Philosophers of  the Arabs

 
Custom Search

 

Dr. Samir Amin

 

Samir Amin (1931-2018) was an Egyptian Marxist economic thinker known for his criticism of liberal capitalist globalization, which he said entrenches dependence on major industrialized countries (center and periphery), and for presenting an alternative theory of development based on the role played by the state in organizing production and financial processes and managing relations with the outside world for the benefit of the local community.

His life

Samir Amin was born on September 3, 1931, in Cairo, the son of an Egyptian father and a French mother, both doctors. He spent his childhood and adolescence in Port Said, studying at the French Lycée, where he obtained his baccalaureate in 1947. From 1947 to 1957, he studied in France, where he obtained a doctorate in economics (1957), preceded by diplomas in political science (1952) and statistics (1956).

After receiving his doctorate in 1957, Amin returned to Cairo, where he served from 1957 to 1960 as Director of the Research Department of the Economic Development Organization. Planning for Egypt's future development was going against Amin's vision, so for political reasons, Amin left Cairo to become an advisor to the Ministry of Planning in Bamako, Mali, from 1960 to 1963. This was a time when many African countries were gaining independence. In 1963, Amin was offered a position at the African Institute for Economic Development and PlanningIDEP ). From 1963 to 1970, he worked at this institute in Dakar, established by the United Nations, while simultaneously teaching at the University of Poitiers and later at the universities of Dakar and Paris VIII-Vincennes . In 1970, Amin became Director of IDEP , a position he remained until 1980.

 In 1980, Amin left IDEP and became director of the Forum du Tiers Monde (Third World Forum ), also based in Dakar. This forum is a non-governmental organizationNGO ) whose mission is to link projects, conferences, and transcontinental discussion platforms on development issues from the perspective of Latin America, Africa, and Asia, with a global orientation. In 1996, Amin also accepted the presidency of the World Forum for Alternatives, which sees itself as a counterpart to the World Economic Forum in Davos, and which presented its manifesto "Il est temps de renverser le cours de l'histoire" (It's time to revisit history ).

Dieter Sengasse reviews Samir Amin's scholarly output in his introduction to the 2014 memorial book as follows:

 Samir Amin published nearly 50 books, most of which were translated into several languages. His most important early book is undoubtedly “Accumulation on a World Scale  1970 . Another landmark is “Uneven Development” 1973, which has been translated into many languages. Between these two books, there were numerous publications in which Amin dealt with his theory in the light of country-specific studies (in Egypt, Mali, Guinea, Ghana, the Maghreb, Côte d'Ivoire, Senegal, West Africa in general, and the Arab region). “Class and Nation in History and the Contemporary Crisis” (1979) is another important publication that opens a perspective on global history and development history that transcends narrow discussions of development theory. Amin's analysis of the socialist alternative to development can be found in “The Future of Maoism” (1981). After 1989 and 1990, Amin published several books on globalization and its underlying crisis (e.g., “Empire of Chaos”, 1991). He also offered a critical assessment of current debates, especially in response to postmodern dogmatism, in “Critique of the Zeitgeist” 1997. His book, “US Hegemony and the Eradication of the European Project” (2000), is a brilliant claim for a “European project” as an equivalent to the unquestionable hegemony of the United States in order not to surrender any further—as in the case of the Gulf War and the Kosovo War—to Washington’s dictatorship. Amin later repeatedly lamented that this much-needed European project remained weak and was not in a position to develop its own globalist position. Amin’s characterization is that it collapsed due to surrender to American hegemony. His later works develop his critique of capitalism and his critique of the global power structure (“Beyond Aging Capitalism”, 2002); they also intervene in the debate on cultural movements, intellectual fashions, and postmodernism (“Modernity, Religion, and Democracy”, 2008). In all his publications, Amin was an intelligent analyst, but at the same time, he was always a political writer

His intellectual project

1-   Intellectual roots

Dieter Singas reviews the intellectual roots of Samir Amin's project as follows:

His political leanings, already evident during his time at the École Normale Supérieure, continued in Paris—unsurprisingly, as Paris has always been a cosmopolitan metropolis with an incomparably vibrant intellectual life. The city was a meeting place for intellectuals and students from all over the world, not just from the Francophone regions of Africa. Immediately after his arrival in Paris, Amin joined the French Communist Party ( PCF ) and thus naturally became involved in the political and intellectual debates within the leftist movement and its various factions, which subsequently dominated the intellectual scene in the cosmopolitan French city for several decadesHis subsequent break with Soviet Marxism and its evolutionary model was influenced by his experience during these early years when, along with other Third World students, Amin edited the journal Étudiants Anticolonialistes (Anticolonialists Students). This journal was not always popular with the PCF Central CommitteeA number of Amin's fellow activists rose to leadership positions in the administrations of newly liberated Third World countries, particularly in Africa.         

In 1957, Amin submitted his doctoral dissertation, and one of his supervisors was François Perroux Amin   suggested the title "On the Sources of Underdevelopment: Capitalist Accumulation on a Global Scale." However, this title was too sensitive for Paris in the mid-1950s. His supervisors persuaded him instead to choose a less direct and straightforward title: "The Structural Effects of the International Integration of Pre-Capitalist Economies - A Theoretical Study of the Mechanisms That Led to the Formation of So-called Underdeveloped States." In his dissertation, Amin correctly assumed that the hypothesis that underdevelopment is a product of capitalism  had not previously been considered from the perspective he proposed. His basic idea, as presented in 1957, was that the 'underdeveloped economy' should be considered as an independent unit (referring to itself) but only as a building block in the construction of a world capitalist economy, and that these periphery societies require permanent structural adjustments in relation to the dynamics of reproduction of the world capitalist centers, i.e., the advanced capitalist industrial state.

One must take into account the context of the 1950s. Amin's message was truly new and original within the general framework of discussions on development theory and policy, which were in their initial stages of ascendancy: at that time, what was called desarrollismo was emerging in Latin America which developed further a decade later in discussions of dependence Wallerstein's analysis of the world order came even later. But even the traditional theories of development had not yet become mainstream; their representatives were introduced by the World Bank in 1984   in Pioneers in Development .    Only from the late 1960s onwards could we observe that discussions on development policy were given a major impetus by international institutions, such as UNCTAD the World Bank, and, more recently,   the International Labour Organization (ILO).

It is therefore surprising that Amin produced as early as 1957 such a nuanced and insightful critique of positions taken 10–20 years later by his intellectual opponents. His critique also extended to Soviet Marxism and its evolutionary model of "catching up and overtaking ." These facts did not attract attention at the time because Amin's treatise was not published in book form until 1970 under the broader title of Accumulation at the Global Level 

2-Motives for the project

Then, in the same article, Dieter Singas presents a general picture of the motives that have driven Samir Amin’s intellectual project over a period of sixty years.

 Samir Amin was one of the most important and influential Third World thinkers. In contrast to the many development researchers who emerged in both industrialized and developing countries over the nearly six decades covered by his extensive work, he always adopted a global perspective. Accumulation at the global level: this model for diagnosing the ills in history, the dynamics of the structure, and the development of the world as a whole rather than individual continents, societies, or regions, has become a political and analytical challenge to current analytical and political thinking on development, especially for the new -classical and   Soviet-Marxist schools.

In the chronological context of his thesis, Samir Amin examined three social projects:

Fordism with its associated (at least in Europe) social-democratic welfare state; the Soviet model as the antithesis of capitalist development; and developmentalism as a project of development by catch-up. As early as 1989-1990, but especially during the 1990s and beyond, Amin examined the failure of these three projects in a number of publications. The social-democratic welfare state and its regulatory mechanisms had eroded; the possibilities of political control through the state had diminished due to the globalization of capitalism; and equivalent instruments of control, which could only be arranged through international organizations, had ceased to exist at either the regional or global levels. The Soviet model collapsed due to its own internal contradictions, particularly because the transition from a large-scale to a centralized economy had failed, a consequence (among other reasons) of the absence of political reform. Thus, all hopes placed in this alternative model, which was widespread in developing countries but never shared by Amin, collapsed. Finally, there was the failure of Bandung, which was seen as a hallmark of the "catch-up" development model. This produced a distinction between the Third World into several centers, which Amin considered to be new semi-industrialized states, and the 'marginalized' world of the 'Fourth World', which included not only large areas of the southern continents but also parts of the former socialist states .

It is not surprising that, given these developments, Samir Amin described the situation in what he clearly referred to in one of his books as "The Great Tumult (1991 )" and "The Empire of Chaos (1991)." A world without reliable regulatory mechanisms at the international and global levels, without an inspiring counter-model, and without clear prospects for successful development—a world in which polarization continues to grow, is unbearable at the international and inter-societal levels, and is becoming increasingly police-like. In such a world, the worst of the worst is expected, not to mention other world problems, such as global climate change .

For Samir Amin, the global capitalist crisis has intensified steadily over the past twenty-five years, despite intermittent phases of economic growth that, viewed in retrospect, have not overcome the system's fundamental contradictions: the tendency toward polarization, inequality, and marginalization, all of which have instead intensified. During this period, the "liberal virus" has spread—that is, the tendency toward deregulation (The Liberal Virus, Permanent War and the Americanization of the World, 2003). Amin anticipated the global financial crisis resulting from a combination of rising wage inequality, deregulated financial markets, irresponsible behavior by corporations and businesspeople, and other factors. For example, when he wrote as early as 2001: "But a financial bubble cannot grow indefinitely: one day it will burst. This is already cause for concern. Some reformers are therefore proposing to reduce the risk by eliminating incentives for short-term speculative investment, for example, through a fabulous Tobin tax ."

This development of the financial market—its limitations and the expansion of its self-directed dynamics without any self-correcting mechanism—is a real example of what Amin called “the blind fetishization of the market.” These and other disastrous developments, especially over the past two decades, are the result of political herd instincts, particularly in the behavior of the leading capitalist industrial societies. They all followed the orthodoxy that prevailed in the Anglo-Saxon world: “There is no alternative.” This led Amin to characterize American hegemony, but now it is linked to the development of “collective imperialism,” especially among the societies of the United States or North America, the European Union, and Japan (the triad). This club also attempts to monopolize areas of action that are relevant to the further development of the world: technology, financial flows, access to the world’s raw materials, means of communication and media, as well as weapons of mass destruction. This club shares in collective imperialism the so-called “half-party” countries. The transition from the G8 to the G20 , as has recently happened, at least in terms of the announced decisions, could be a step toward mutual cooperation. The rest of the world will remain “the rest.” Wherever Political concerns make it necessary, and these countries will remain the subject of military intervention. However, given the chaotic situation in many countries around the world, prospects for a successful and cost-effective intervention remain poor . 

Are there ways out of this disastrous situation? Samir Amin has always been not only a perceptive analyst but also a political actor with a clear perspective, which has led to the emergence of a program of action, which Dieter Sengass outlines in the following points:

1.There is a need for a "new beginning toward development," that is, an alternative, critical conception of development, not based on "development by catch-up" but directed toward a non-capitalist alternative to development. According to Amin, this would be "socialist development," but not in the sense of the one-formula socialist development projects implemented by Soviet Marxism. This new beginning must be grounded in social movements. This assumption is the driving force behind Amin's global activities, which have not waned in various NGOs—because the elites are unlikely to propose such a new beginning.

2. Furthermore, and in a logical consistency, Samir Amin argues that without the process of separation (which is not identical with secession), there will be no new beginning toward development. Separation means making external relations subservient to the needs of the internal structure, and not the other way around—for example, there is no unilateral reconciliation with prevailing trends at the global level .

3.  Samir Amin passionately calls for transforming the world into regions for a multipolar world (2005). This represents a call for a regionally oriented "collective self-reliance" as a basis for reshaping the structure of global relations and organizing needs agreed upon at the global level.

He adds,

It may be asked: Are these points, which together constitute a program of action, and which we have briefly presented here, nothing more than an expression of an ideal world, a "utopia"? Amin's answer to this question is: Yes, but these proposals, which point the way forward, follow the logic of "creative utopia." "History is not governed by the infallible successive steps of pure economic law." It is created by the social reactions of these tendencies, which express themselves in these laws and determine the social conditions within which these laws operate. The forces of asymmetry have an impact and influence both real history and the pure logic of capitalist accumulation .

Samir Amin was exposed to such oppositional police logic throughout his life, and he himself participated convincingly in controversial debates about this type of logic at the global level.

His approach

The approach followed by Samir Amin is generally Marxist (historical materialism), but it is also based on scientific, analytical, empirical (i.e., experimental in the social sense) methodology, through which he accurately analyzes political, economic, and social reality. In his introduction to the previously mentioned memorial book on Samir Amin, Dieter Sengass presents a picture of Amin's methodological approach as follows:

Samir Amin is a distinguished thinker with a truly global outlook and a prolific output. His scholarly work overcomes the over-specialization that characterizes many development planners and theorists. Their narrow scientific approach and adherence to paradigms are alien to Amin. His ability to conduct evidence-based research, from both historical and comparative perspectives, in every sense of the word is truly rare. His analyses always take into account socio-structural conditions and considerations of political power, and his inclinations, ideologies, and ways of thinking point the way forward. This has made him an inexhaustible source of inspiration through his historical-materialist approach that rejects orthodoxy and dogmatism. Amin's driving force has always been to recognize new trends in development, revise his own position, initiate dialogues, and engage in ongoing ones. The source of this intellectual and political drive has been an incessant thirst for knowledge and a dialectical inclination that extends from analytical contributions to pre-capitalist world historical developments to reflections on development projects in their narrowest contexts. His work represents radical empirical critiques of capitalism, but it also offers groundbreaking proposals for the desired future. As Samir Amin once argued, he was never a “ tiers-mondiste (i.e., his work focused solely on Third World issues), but always a “ mondiste ”   with a globalist bent. This—and not only this—distinguishes him from many of those who occupy prominent places in the “ Who’s Who ”   of social and development theory, and more recently, global analysis. His scholarly achievements over his long life demonstrate a freedom of thought that has always resisted various inhibitions.

From a more precise perspective, Samir Amin presents the approach he followed in his project in the introduction to his work "The Law of Globalized Value," entitled "Marx Without Borders." Amin presents himself as a developer of Marxist theory, extending the Marxist critique of capitalism to its global dimensions. He also expands the concept of capitalist exploitation from the exploitation of the poor classes (the proletariat) by capitalists to the exploitation of poor countries (the countries of the South, the periphery) by capitalist states (global imperialism, the center). This requires developing Marx's law of value into the law of "globalized" value—that is, how global imperialist states are systematically able to achieve capitalist accumulation through the exploitation of the countries of the South. It also requires accepting the idea of a state founded on a national class of capitalists within the framework of the socialist state. This, too, represents a departure from the narrow framework of Marxism, which opposes the concept of the state in favor of proletarian internationalism.

Amin first presents the essence of Marx's ideas in the following lines:

Marx was the first to offer a radical critique of the real world in our time. This radical critique of capitalism allows, indeed requires, the discovery of the basis of commodity alienation and the exploitation of labor that accompanies it. The fundamental value of the concept of value stems from this radical critique. It alone allows for the understanding of the objective laws that govern the reproduction of the system, which exist beneath the surface movements we observe when observing reality. Marx adds to his critique of the real world a critique of the discourses concerning this reality, whether philosophical, economic, social, historical, or political. This radical critique reveals their ultimately defensive nature, which legitimizes the practices of the dominant power of capital .

Then he presents his vision of how to build on these ideas so that they can be developed as reality develops, i.e. transforming them from closed, dogmatic concepts into open (without borders) concepts.

To be a Marxist means to complete the work begun by Marx, even if that beginning is extremely vigorous. It does not mean stopping with Marx, but starting from him. Marx is not a prophet whose conclusions are all "correct" and "final," and his work is not a closed theory. Marx is "without borders," because the criticism he began without borders always needs to be completed and criticized (Marxism, as it is formed at a given moment, must be subjected to Marxist criticism). Marxism must always enrich itself with radical criticism and consider any innovations produced by the system as new fields of human knowledge.

But Marx left a school, and historical Marxist schools followed in his footsteps. They clashed and fought (sometimes fiercely) as religious schools do, but their interpretations are inherently "anti-Marxist." A Marxist can only be an independent Marxist, but until recently, those who tried to be independent were described by traditional Marxist schools as deviants. Perhaps their situation is no longer so bad today .

These historical Marxisms, which I describe as popular and which occupied the forefront of the stage, were generally addressing two discourses :

On the one hand, there is proper economics, which criticizes and complements Ricardian economics, which it considers inadequate, and categorically opposes so-called neoclassical economics, a worthless ideological discourse. On the other hand, there is the science of societies, namely historical materialism, which is built on the fundamental concept that class struggle is the driving force of history. These two wings of Marxism complement each other, and their unity stems from the philosophy of dialectical materialism. We do not intend here to refute this reading of Marxism or offer an alternative. Rather, we will limit ourselves to examining how the laws of economics and class struggle are related within the framework of capitalism .

The subtitle of Capital, "A Critique of Political Economy," does not mean a critique of bad (Ricardian) political economy in favor of good (Marxist) political economy. Rather, it is a critique of so-called economics, revealing its true nature (i.e., what the bourgeoisie claims about the nature of its practices). It is also a critique of the epistemological value of this economy, exposing its limitations, and calling for understanding that this so-called science, which claims to be independent of historical materialism, cannot be independent of it .

After proving the possibility of viewing Marxist thought as an open thought that is capable of addition and development, Amin presents his idea of building on this thought as follows:

My thesis is as follows: a) that historical materialism is the essence of Marxism, and therefore: b) that the epistemological status of the laws of capitalist economics makes them subject to the laws of historical materialism; c) that under the capitalist mode of production the laws of economics take on a theoretical status different from those under pre-capitalist modes; d) that the laws of economics only appeared with the capitalist system of production; e) that the laws of capitalist economics have an objective existence; f) that these laws are subject, in the final analysis, to the law of value .

Thus, in my opinion, the class struggle under capitalism in general, and in the imperialist world in particular, operates on a specific economic basis, and in turn changes that basis .

We will treat these concepts in the book in the following general order: 1) Accumulation in the capitalist system of production (Chapter 1); 2) Monetary equilibrium and the theory of the rate of interest (Chapter 2); 3) The division of surplus product between capitalists and landlords and the theory of land rent (Chapter 3); 4) Accumulation on the world level in the imperialist system, the hierarchy of prices of labor power and imperialist rent (Chapter 4).

Amin adds his founding additions to Marxist thought,

My careful reading of Capital and other works by Marx and Engels began early in my university studies (1948-1955). I also carefully read the works of the economists criticized by Marx (Smith, Ricardo, Bastiat, Say, and others), preferring to simply peruse their theses as they appear in university economics courses My reading of Marx was certainly a source of great satisfaction and confirmed the power of his thought, but a feeling of dissatisfaction remained because I did not find in him a satisfactory answer to the "backwardness" of contemporary Asian and African societies. Nor did I find satisfaction in reading those works, which were not published in French until 1960 (the Grundrisse) .

Rather than dismissing Marx as outdated, I concluded that his work was incomplete and that his analysis failed to capture the global dimension. This was partly because his analysis failed to include the global dimension of capitalism, and partly because it failed to connect the issue of power (the political) with the economy (capitalism and its predecessors).

Given that the deficiency in Marxist thought was centered on the absence of an explanation for the backwardness of Asian and African societies (i.e., the Third World countries), it becomes obvious that Amin would attempt to fill this gap. The idea of the opposition between the worker and the owner of capital expanded, so that "the worker" became "the countries of the Third World, the periphery," capital became "the countries of the capitalist world, the center," and the issue of "surplus capital" became the issue of "unequal development." This is shown as follows:

My thinking has focused on the issue of (unequal) development that characterizes the reality of global capitalism, as evidenced by my doctoral dissertation, "Accumulation on the World Scale," submitted in 1957. This was the starting point for my work over the next fifty years, and I will not enumerate the stages of this thinking here, contenting myself with referring to my subsequent books: "Uneven Development" (1973), "Unequal Exchanges" (1973), and "The Law of Value and Historical Materialism" ( 1977) .

Benefiting from Marx's rigorous method, I carefully read the fundamental works of popular economics produced after Marx, especially by Böhm-Bawerk, Walras, and Keynes, who laid the foundations of "subjective" popular economics. This critical reading began first with the "Accumulation" thesis of 1957, and then with "Uneven Development." Reading these works convinced me of the ideological nature, in the functional sense, of bourgeois economics, which followed and was hostile to Marxism .

Marx did not limit himself to a theoretical response to his predecessors, but confronted them with a wealth of organized facts. Therefore, I considered that a theoretical response to the bourgeois economists was insufficient, and that a systematic collection of facts that revealed the globalized path of capitalism was necessary. I began collecting this material in Accumulation and continued it with the books of the 1970s. I paid special attention to the developments taking place during that period, particularly the first awakening of the countries of the South, represented by the Bandung period 1955-1980 ) .

My studies then took two directions: development economics, on the one hand, and a deeper analysis of markets (and the role of expectations), on the other. The first direction seemed to me rather dull, barely going beyond the concept of "necessary and insurmountable stages of growth." I had offered a radical critique of this common, mechanistic view even before Rostov expressed his criticism in 1960. Never since have the agencies entrusted with serving these policies (the World Bank, "cooperation" programs, or universities) gone beyond such nonsense .

The second trend has been to pursue this common deviation to its logical conclusion—the concept of "generalized markets"—a fictional economic construct that bears no relation to capitalism as it exists. The necessary conclusion of this deviation is the empty and utopian concept of "expectations." At the same time, this deviation, which claims to be empirical, gathers an increasing number of heterogeneous facts to incorporate into its theses. The use of mathematical treatment is not in itself objectionable, but the increasing complexity of these treatments does not negate the illogical and empty nature of the issues raised by their users: "expectations ."

However, neither the criticism I have leveled at the popular theories and their 'applications', nor the counter-arguments I have made in return, by incorporating the ordered facts into a general theory describing globalized capitalism as it actually is, seem to me sufficient to fully understand the reality of uneven development .

Indeed, the link between the political/ideological/cultural dimension and the economic dimension is the essential axis of the unavoidable historical materialist reading. In this regard, my reading of Marx convinced me that reading these early formulations calls for daring to move forward. I attempted this, first by proposing the concept of the "tributary production system" as the basis for a large family of advanced pre-capitalist class societies, where the dominant power/subordinate economy nexus stands in contrast to the inverse nexus in capitalist societies. From this, I deduced some important results regarding the forms of alienation in ancient historical societies and modern capitalist society. To explore the movement of concrete contradictions operating within these societies to accelerate or decelerate progress toward capitalism, I attempted to link the issues raised in historical materialism with those related to the economic dimension. This is what reading the two books, "Uneven Development" and "The Law of Value and Historical Materialism," reveals. This confirms what I previously said: that as a Marxist, I do not stop with Marx or his successors (Lenin and Mao) in constructing historical Marxisms, but rather begin with him .

Finally, Amin the essence of his contribution to Marxist thought and its consequences in the following lines:

The central focus of my efforts is the establishment of a "law of globalized value" that is consistent, on the one hand, with the foundations of capitalism's law of value as discovered by Marx, and, on the other, with the reality of uneven global development This is what I dare to describe—without false modesty—as my multiple contributions to enriching Marxism without borders, especially with regard to their importance for understanding the nature and extent of the major contradictions and associated conflicts within the framework of contemporary capitalism .

Within these scattered contributions, I have not hesitated to "complement" Marx's theses, or even to "correct" them. I point to the role of credit in achieving accumulation (and in response to Rosa Luxemburg's question about the realization of surplus value), as well as to my analysis of the determination of the interest rate and land rent and my alternative proposals in this area. On these issues, I refer the reader to my book “Uneven Development “.

My main contribution concerns the transition from the law of value to the law of globalized value, based on the globalized hierarchy of labor-power prices around its value. This globalization of value, along with practices related to access to natural resources, is the basis of imperialist rent. I claim that this is the driving force behind the actual contradictions of capitalism/imperialism as they exist, and the associated conflicts in which classes and nations are entangled with all their complex interconnections. I claim that our reading of the history of the twentieth and twenty-first centuries will not depart from the history of the emergence or "awakening" of peoples and nations on the periphery of the globalized capitalist-imperialist system .

There are, undoubtedly, many other contributions by Marxists other than myself that enrich Marx's concept of without borders, but this is not the place to enumerate them .

My theoretical analysis of the globalized capitalist system, as it exists, begins with the law of value, as Marx established it in the first part of Capital. This is the only valid starting point; without the concept of value, the concept of capital accumulation is meaningless. Thus, it is impossible to escape the detour through value and simply review the immediate reality (actual prices), as required by positivist/empirical methods of study .

Thus, the analysis I will present will consider the three stages of value transformation: 1) to “production prices”; 2) then to “market prices” (which are monopoly prices under contemporary capitalism); 3) then to “globalized prices” (under the globalized imperialist system.

The first of these transformations, which is mentioned in the first chapters of the third part of Capital, is indispensable for understanding the commodity alienation that controls economic and social life under capitalism, and which gives the laws that govern its reproduction their true place .

The second of these transformations, related to the transformation of production prices into market prices, was partially addressed by Marx in the third part of Capital, when he spoke about the distribution of surplus value in the case of agricultural land ownership .

We must then examine the distortion of the price system resulting from the emergence of monopolies, and in particular, take into account the dangerous transformation of the system of expanded reproduction that resulted after the First World War, and even more so after the Second World War, from the massive expansion of a tertiary sector to absorb surplus value. With the concept of surplus they presented, Baran and Sweezy responded to the challenge and unwaveringly enriched and expanded Marxist theory. I claim that those Marxists who refuse to recognize the central importance of Baran and Sweezy's contribution lack the capacity to offer an effective critique of contemporary capitalism, and their Marxism remains confined to commentary on and explanation of Marx's texts .

 The central goal of my reflections is the third transformation, which allows us to move from the law of value at the highest levels of abstraction (i.e., the capitalist system of production) to what I call the law of globalized value, operating at the level of the polarized and already existing system of capitalism/imperialism. Only this transformation allows us to measure the magnitude of imperialist rent, which is the basis of the polarization deepened and reproduced by the global expansion of capitalism .

It is impossible to "understand the world" through a realistic analysis of capitalism as it exists, outside the framework of addressing these shifts in the concept of value. Likewise, it is impossible to develop a strategy for "changing the world" without relying on these foundations. Conversely, the positivist/empirical methods of popular economics do not allow us to understand the world and appreciate the challenges facing workers and peoples, let alone change it. Moreover, popular economics does not attempt to transcend capitalism, which it considers "the end of history," but rather merely to legitimize the fundamental principles of capitalism and describe how it should be governed .

I believe this work, which draws heavily on my book “The Law of Value and Historical Materialism”, is timely, as the current crisis revolves primarily around the various possible developments of social and international relations that shape the law of value under the combined influence of conflicts in contemporary capitalist societies in the core and periphery, as well as conflicts between dominant imperialist societies and subjugated periphery societies, conflicts that challenge the continued dominance of what I call “late (contemporary) capitalism of generalized, privatized, and globalized monopolies.”

3-His theory of development

Amin's contribution thus focuses on his theory of development, which is based on fundamental elements of Marxist thought, as well as fundamental elements of his conceptions of the development of Marxist thought, as well as contemporary transformations in capitalist thought and its practical developments. This theory is scattered throughout a large number of Amin's works over a period of approximately fifty years. In his introduction to the aforementioned memorial book on Samir Amin, Dieter Sengass provides a brief overview of the basic elements of this theory as follows:

What then was Amin's contribution to global and development analysis: that of a scholar, a contemporary analyst, and a thoughtful debater, but always from a knowledge-based political perspective?

From a global historical perspective, development is a concept identical to capitalist development. However, unlike Marx and bourgeois economics, Amin always relied on the observation that real capitalism can only be analyzed from a global perspective. Hence, his title indicated the path to follow:   Accumulation on a World Scale (L'accumulation à l'échelle mondiale). However, Amin does not assume that the plunder of the southern continents during the early colonial and mercantile phase caused a leap toward agrarian and industrial capitalism within the early successful industrial countries. Nor does he assume that industrial development in the so-called centers or metropolitan (i.e., urban) cities of capitalism could have existed without the peripheries in the southern continents (zones of occupation, informal empires, etc.). During the early phase of agrarian and industrial capitalist development, which was successful only in Europe, this process facilitated the existence of the periphery but was not its functional cause. The developmental dynamics of the centers resulted from immanent dynamics of accumulation, the structural and political background of which was the result of an agrarian revolution as a result of the process of defeudalization. This produced a simultaneous or successive industrialization that first led to the production of simple, non-durable products for the mass market; from this, and simultaneously or shortly thereafter, a new capitalist system developed; the products of this capitalist sector increased their productivity significantly in the agricultural and consumer sectors and later also in the capital sector.   For Amin, it is important to note from a secular evolutionary perspective that in the European centers of capitalist development, as a result of successful political struggles, the rise in real wages followed the rise in productivity in the economy as a whole; this facilitated the creation of a domestic market dynamic that stimulated productivity increases in all sectors. This dynamic was created very early in the United States and in the European colonies of Australia and New Zealand by the relative shortage of labor .

Just as the dynamics of urban accumulation cannot be explained solely through economics, but also through an analysis of socio-structural development and sets of political conflicts (political conflicts with open historical and principled consequences), so too the dynamics of accumulation in the peripheries cannot be conceptualized solely through economics. For Amin, they emerged as the peripheries, as external territories isolated from the capitalist centers, were forced to integrate within an unequal international division of labor, and as a result, a structure of asymmetric interdependence developed. In a way that differs from how the idea of dualism underlies modernization theories, this type of integration in the global market leads to a strengthening of the image of the "periphery," since, as a result of the dynamics of accumulation prevalent in the peripheries, a reservoir of cheap labor remains inexhaustible, regardless of whether the economy in the isolated regions is actually based on agriculture, mineral extraction, or the early stages of industrialization ("import-substituting industrialization," industrialization through import substitution to encourage local production) .

Why does the pool of cheap labor not diminish? Why does not productivity and wage growth in the periphery balance out? Why does not a broad diffusion and concentration of capital occur? The answer can be found in the model of the dynamics of peripheral accumulation, which Amin gradually developed based on case studies of numerous countries and using a large number of comparative observations. These facts can be described relatively simply: the dynamics of peripheral accumulation are systematically deviant. As a background, they lack an agrarian revolution in the broadest sense. They gain their dynamism from an export economy based on exclaves ,   whose counterpart is an import sector of "luxury goods," defined as demand from the consumer portion of earnings. What is lacking in this type of accumulation dynamics is "automatic central development": the inevitable feedback loop of a broad consumer goods sector and a capital equipment sector (i.e., equipment that was previously produced locally) dependent on increased agricultural productivity.

From this it becomes clear that for Samir Amin, the question of agriculture was and remains of central strategic relevance to development. Much of his empirical research has dealt with this problem. As an unavoidable consequence, for him, the question of agriculture was not simply a question of land distribution but could also be understood as the problem of how legal certainty for this sector (property rights) could emerge and the extent to which a corresponding industrial sector would be willing and able to supply the goods and infrastructure that would enable the development of a dynamic agricultural sector. 

From Amin's analysis, it can be argued that the transition from a dynamic of accumulation in the periphery to economic development based on urban capitalism remains unlikely, if not impossible. This leads to his call for decoupling. Decoupling, then, is defined as the surrender of a state's external relations to the logic of genuine internal development. This contrasts with the prevailing orientation toward the periphery, which must satisfy the needs of urban capitalism with the inevitable consequences of polarizing current capitalism at the global level: its formulation of an urban capitalism and a periphery dependent on it. Such a strategy of "automatic centralized" development through "decoupling" is inconceivable without active state intervention. Therefore, the role of the state, in conjunction with interested socialist parties, is to devise this hybrid strategy, the goal of which should be the selective use of opportunities in the global market—as long as they are compatible with the state's own project—in order to consolidate development dynamics in the broadest sense .  

For Amin, it was clear that this alternative to development (separation, not secession) entailed corresponding political preconditions. The countries to which he applied his case studies, initially limited to North and Sub-Saharan Africa, taught him that such an elite, i.e., a national bourgeoisie oriented toward a national project, did not exist and was not in the process of formation. Instead, he saw the emergence of a comprador bourgeoisie (or local agents of global capitalism) everywhere. This comprador bourgeoisie—and this was confirmed by empirical material—saw its future only in the integration of its countries within the framework of a global capitalist market with an asymmetric structure, from which they directly benefited. Separation could only be an instrument for a type of development with a different orientation—a development beyond capitalism (including its variant, state socialism). These considerations prompted Amin to analyze in detail the Chinese development strategy 

This model of development, which Amin continually refined and corrected at the detailed level, directly contradicted the linear evolutionary model of development. His approach challenged the bourgeois or neoclassical evolutionary alternative to development theory. Amin directly opposed the evolutionary concept of " desarrollismo " which emerged through the CEPAL school (Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean). He considered the latter, although plausible (though not entirely convincing), politically illusory. With this model, Amin also opposed the developmentalist ideology of Soviet Marxism, which attracted much sympathy among the new elites in the Third World during the independence period as well as during the post-colonial and state-building years. As a result, during the 1970s and 1980s, Amin was deeply skeptical and radically critical of a number of prominent development policy and planning programmes: for example, the New World Economic Order (and its operational concepts), the Basic Needs Strategy, and the ILO's informal sector programme .        

From his perspective, the goal could not be "catching up and then overtaking," but only another form of development: "doing something else": a different development strategy for these groups of the population, who were systematically marginalized and discriminated against, requiring their politicization and democratization. Having emancipated the people as a result of the successful struggle for independence, Amin now focused on revolutionary social movements, a revolution of the large groups. Economic development was always, and still is, for Amin a political economy and even more a process of cultural revolution, because "doing something else" is unthinkable without a corresponding political consciousness.

His most important works

Books in French

1. Egypt Nassérienne , Minute Editions, 1964. (with the pseudonym Hassan

Riad), Translation into Spanish.

2. Learn about development experiences in Africa : Mali, Guinée and others.

Ghana , Paris, PUF, 1965.

3. Economie du Maghreb , Paris, Minuit Editions, 1966,

Vol. 1: The colonization and decolonization ;

Vol. 2: These perspectives .

Translation into Polish.

4. The development of capitalism in the Côte d'Ivoire , Minute Editions, 1967,

2nd Ed. Postface 1971.

5. Le Monde des Affaires Sénégalais , Minute Editions, 1969, Translation into

Japanese

6. From Congo Français to the UDEAC, history of the African Equatorial Economy1880 – 1968 , Paris-Dakar, Anthropos, 1979, in collaboration with Catherine Coquery.

7. Le Maghreb moderne , Paris, Minuit Editions, 1970. Translation into English, Arabic

8. Accumulation to the World Cup, criticizing the sous - development theory ,

Anthropos, 1970, Coll. 10–18. Translation into English, Spanish, Italian,

Arabic, Swedish, Greek, Serbo-Croatic, Japanese, Chinese, New Edition with

Preface, Economica 1988.

9. African bloque, economic policy of colonization 1880 –

1970 , Editions de Minuit, 1971. Translation into English.

10. English development , Minute Editions, 1973. Translation into English,

Arabic, Spanish, German, Portuguese, Greek, Italian, Korean, Danish, Japanese, Chinese

11. The original change and the value of the money , Anthropos 1973, with a contribution by JC Saigal. Translation into Italian, Spanish, English, Arabic, Japanese. New edition, Econo-mica, 1988.

12. The question pays and capitalism , in collaboration with Kostas Vergopoulos, Anthropos 1974. Translation into Spanish, Portuguese.

13. La crise de l'impérialisme , in collaboration with Faire, Hussein and Massiah, Editions de Minuit, 1975. Translation into Spanish, Greek, Italian, Danish,

Portuguese, Arabic.

14. Impérialisme et le development in English , Minute Editions 1976. Translation into Portuguese, Greek, Japanese.

15. Impérialisme and sous development in Africa , Anthropos, 1976. New Edition, Economica 1988.

16. The Arab nation: nationalism and classes , Minuit Editions, 1976.

Translation into English, Arabic, Japanese.

17. The story of the value and the material history , Minute Editions, 1977.

Translation into English, Portuguese, Greek, Japanese, Spanish, Arabic.

18. Class and nation in history and contemporary craze , Minute Editions

1979. Translation into English, Spanish, Arabic, Japanese, Portuguese, Greek.

19. L'économie arabe contemporaine , Minuit Editions, 1980. Translation into English, Danish, Arabic, Japanese, Portuguese.

20. Lavenir du maoïsme , Minute Editions 1981. Translation into English,

Arabic, Korean, Japanese, Portuguese, Turkish, Bengal.

21. Irak et Syrie 1960 – 1980 , Minuit Editions 1982.

22. La crise, quelle crise? Maspero 1982, in collaboration with G. Arrighi, AG Frank and I. Wallerstein. Translation into English, Spanish, German, Turkish.

23. The deconnexion, to sort out the global system , Discover 1985.

Translation into Spanish, Italian, English, Japanese.

24. Eurocentrism, critique of ideology , Economica 1988. Translation into

English, Spanish, Italian, Japanese, Portuguese, Norwegian, Turkish, Chinese.

25. The development failed in Africa and in the middle of the world , L'Harmattan, 1989. Translation into English, Spanish.

26. The large number? La Découverte 1991, in collaboration with G. Arrighi, A. G. Frank and I. Wallerstein. Translation into English.

27. The Empire of chaos, the new mondialisation capitalist , L'Harmattan

1991. Translation into English, Arabic, Spanish, German, Turkish.

28. Itineraire Intellectual, Regards on the Demi - Siècle 1945 – 1990 , L'Harmattan 1993. Translation into Arabic, English, Italian, Spanish, Turkish, Chinese.

29. Ethnicity in the Nations, with a contribution from Joseph Vansy ,

Harmattan 1994.

30. La gestion capitaliste de la crise , L'Harmattan 1995. Translation into Italian.

31. Les defies de la mondialisation, L'Harmattan 1996. Translation into Spanish, Italian, German, Portuguese, Chinese.

32. Critique de l'Air du Temps , L'Harmattan 1997. Translation into English,

Italian, Tutkish, Greek, Spanish, Arabic, Chinese.

33. The organization of the organization - Universities and the efficiency of the European project , L'Harmattan 2000. Translation into Italian, German, Spanish, Chinese, Greek, Arabic.

34. This old capitalism, for a non-American country , PUF Actuel Marx 2002. Translation into English, Arabic, Spanish, Greek, German, Polish, Japanese, Italian

35. The virus is free, its permanent status and its American origin; Le

Temps des Cerises , Paris 2003. Translation into Arabic, English, Italian,

Spanish, Turkish, Swedish, Russian, Portuguese, Chinese, Polish.

36. The Arabic language, including social and media perspectives ; incollaboration with Ali El Kenz, L'Harmattan, 2003. Translation into Arabic, English, Swedish, Italian.

37. For many people ; Syllepse 2005. Translation into English, Spanish.

38. For the international cinema; Le temps des cerises , 2006. Translation into

Italian, Spanish, English, Turkish.

39. Capitalism to civilisation ; Syllepse 2008. Translation into Spanish,

English, Turkish

40. The world, political panorama and personnel from the country of Bandoung; Le Ceremony time , 2008.

41. Modernity, Religions, Democracy, Critique of Eurocentrism, Critique of

culturalism ; Parangon, 2008. Translation into Turkish, English.

42. Sur la crise, sortir de la crise du capitalisme ou sortir du capitalisme en crise; Le Temps des Cerises , Paris 2009. Translation into Spanish, Italian, English.

43. The heart of the world's value; Le temps des cerises , 2011. Translation into English, Arabic, Spanish, German.

44. Samir Amin, intellectual organization at the Sud administration service;

Entrepreneurs and selected texts by Demba Moussa Dembélé , Codesria 2011.

45. Deliver capitalism ; Contradictions, Bruxelles 2011.

46. The Arabic language in the long period, the Arabic print? the temperatures Cerises 2011. Translation into English, Spanish, Italian.

47. Implosion of contemporary capitalism, Automation of capitalism, print templates people? Delga 2012

Books in English

 1. The Maghreb in the Modern World , Penguin, 1970.

2. Neo colonialism in West Africa , Penguin, 1973.

3. Accumulation on a World Scale , 2 vol. Monthly Review Press, New York, 1974.

4. Unequal Development , Monthly Review Press, New York, 1976.

5. Imperialism and Unequal Development (includes “The end of a Debate”),

Monthly Review Press, New York, 1977.

6. The Arab Nation , Zed, London, 1978.

7. The Law of Value and Historical Materialism , Monthly Review Press, New York 1978.

8. Class and Nation, Historically and in the current crisis , Monthly Review

Press, New York, 1980.

9. The Arab Economy today , Zed, London 1982.

10. Dynamic of Global Crisis , Monthly Review Press, 1982, in Collaboration

with G. Arrighi, A. G. Frank and I. Wallerstein.

11. The Future of Maoism , Monthly Review Press, New York 1983; simultaneously Daanish Books, India 2002

12. Eurocentrism , Monthly Review Press, New York, 1989.

13. Delinking, towards a polycentric world , Zed, London 1990.

14. Maldevelopment, Anatomy of a global failure , Zed, London 1990.

15. Transforming the Revolution , Monthly Review Press, 1990, in collaboration with G. Arrighi, A. G. Frank and I. Wallerstein.

16. The Empire of Chaos , Monthly Review Press, New York 1992.

17. Re - reading the Post War period, An intellectual Itinerary , Monthly Review Press, New York 1994.

18. Capitalism in the Age of Globalisation , Zed, London 1996. Translation into Spanish, Turkish, Italian.

19. Specters of capitalism, A critique of current intellectual fashions , Monthly Review Press, New York 1998; Simultaneously Daanish Books, India, 2002

20. Obsolescent capitalism , Zed 2003.

21. The liberal virus ; Pluto, London 2004.

22. Beyond US hegemony ; Zed, London 2006; simultaneously Daanish Books, India 2006.

23. A life looking forward, Memoirs of an independent Marxist ; Zed, London

2006. Translation into Spanish.

24. The world we wish to see : revolutionary objectives for the 21st Century ; MR Press, NY, 2008.

25. From Capitalism to civilization, Reconstructing the socialist perspective ; Tulika Books Delhi, 2010.

26. Ending the crisis of capitalism or ending capitalism? Pambazuka, Oxford 2010.

27. Global History, A view from the South ; Pambazuka, Oxford 2010.

28. Eurocentrism (new enlarged ed); MR Press, NY and Pambazuka, Oxford 2010.

29. The law of worldwide value ; MRPress, NY 2010.

30. Maldevelopment, Anatomy of a Global Failure ; Fahamu Books, Oxford 2011.

31. The people's spring, the future of the Arab revolutions ; Fahamu 2012.

Books in Spanish

1. Hassan Riad , Egypt, actual phenomenon , Nova Terra, Barcelona, 1969.

2. Categories and Fundamentals of Capitalism , Nuestro Tiempo, Mexico, 1973.

3. El capitalismo periferico , Nuestro Tiempo, Mexico, 1973.

4. Desarrollo desigual , Nuestro Tiempo, Mexico, 1973.

5. Capitalismo periferico y comercio internacional , Ediciones Periferia, Buenos Aires, 1974.

6. The original design, including the social forms of capitalism

periferico , Libros de confrontacion, Barcelona, 1974.

7. Elogio del socialismo, El capitalismo: una crisi estructural, feminismo y

lucha de clases (Con Eynard and Stuckey), Ed. Anagrama, Barcelona, 1975.

8. The acumulation in the world , Siglo XXI, Buenos Aires and Mexico, 1975.

9. Sobre la transmission , Ed. Zero, Madrid, 1975.

10. Los Angeles, US of plastics, this is a crisis of imperialism, global influences y cultural areas , Ed. Anagrama, Barcelona, 1975.

11. Classes and places in the materialismo historico , El Viejo Topo, Barcelona, 1979.

12. The highest value and historic materialism , cultural economic fund,

Mexico, 1981.

13. La deconnexion, hacia un sistema mundial policentrico , IEPALA, Madrid, 1988.

14. El Eurocentrismo —Siglo XXI, Mexico, 1989.

15. Capitalismo y systema mundo , Lafarga editions, Barcelona, 1993.

16. El Juego de la Estrategia en el Mediterraneo , IEPALA, Madrid, 1993.

17. The Fracasso del Sarollo in Africa and in the Tercer Mundo, a political analysis ,

IEPALA, Madrid, 1994.

18. Los desafios de la mundializacion , Siglo XXI, Mexico, 1997.

19. The capitalism in the global era, Paidos, Barcelona, Buenos Aires,

Mexico, 1998.

20. Los fantasmas del capitalismo , El Ancora, Bogota, 1999.

21. Miradas a un medio siglo, Itinerario intellectual 1945 – 1990 , IEPALA,

Madrid; Plural—La Paz, 1999.

22. The hegemonismo of the Unidos Estados and the proyecto desvanecimiento

europeo ; Ed. El Viejo Topo; Madrid 2001.

23. Critica del nuestro tiempo ; Siglo XXI, Mexico, 2001.

24. What is the cause of capitalism ? El Viejo Topo, Barcelona 2003.

25. El imperialismo colectivo ; CTA, Buenos Aires 2004.

26. For a multipolar world; The view is topo ; Barcelona 2005.

27. Classes sociales, nationalities, and institutions in the global history ; Ed Garetto, Argentina 2005.

28. The original design ; Ed Garetto, Argentina 2005.

29. Intercambio desigual ; Ed Garetto, Argentina; 2005.

30. Sobre el desarrollo desigual en la historia universal ; Ed Garetto, Argentina 2005.

31. The virus liberal ; Ed Garetto, Argentina 2006; Hacer, Barcelona, 2007.

32. For international quinta ; The view topo, Barcelona 2007.

33. Memorias ; El Viejo Topo, Barcelona, 2008.

34. Transactions and alternatives in debate; America Latina on the move , no. 436, 2008.

35. The imperio del caus, the new mundializacion capitaliste ; IEPALA, Madrid 2008.

36. El socialismo del siglo XXI, Reconstruir la perspectiva socialiste ; IEPALA, Madrid 2009.

37. La crisis, salir de la crisis del capitalismo o salir del capitalismo en crisis ; El Top Life, Barcelona, 2009.

38. Primavera in Arabic, the world in Arabic during the course ; El Viejo Topo, Barcelona 2011.

Research

·                     Economic Globalization and Political Universalism: Two Opposing Themes , Journal of World System Research

·                     Economic Globalism and Political Universalism: Conflicting Issues?, Journal of World System Research, 2000.

·                     Imperialism of the United States, Europe, and the Middle East , a monthly review.

·                     US Imperialism, Europe, and the Middle East, Monthly Review, Nov. 2004

·                     Nation, State, and Classes in the Arab World - Al-Mustaqbal Al-Arabi Magazine

Dialogues

·                     Samir Amin: We are witnessing the autumn of capitalism, and we are not yet in the spring of peoples - Beginnings

·                     We need a consensual, non-authoritarian, humane globalization - Qantara website  

·                     Samir Amin: Arab countries are experiencing the "militarization of globalization" - Al-Bidaya Newspaper

·                     Globalization is an ancient phenomenon - Qantara website

Articles about him

·                     Dr. Samir Amin, the Marxist - Fouad Al-Nimri

·                     Thinking with Samir Amin, Imperialism and Anarchy - Amer Mohsen

·                     On Samir Amin's Criticism of Nationalist and Islamic Discourses - Farhan Saleh

·                     Samir Amin, the thinker who heralded the return of socialism - Muhammad al-Hamamsi

·                     Samir Amin... and the Arab Spring - Hashem Saleh

·                     My Memoirs: A Past to Guard the Future - Abdelmalek Ashhaboun

·                     Samir Amin and the Future of Marxism - Mr. Ould Abah

Texts

·                     The Law of Globalized Value, translated by Saad Al-TawilChapter One: “The Basic Status of the Law of Value.”

·                     After the Fall of Capitalism, translated by Fahmiyya Sharaf al-Din and Sanaa Abu ShakraIntroduction and Chapter One "The Political Economy of the Twentieth Century."

·                     Accumulation on a Global Scale, translated by Hassan QubaisChapter One: “Uneven International Specialization and International Capital Flows.”

Sources

·                     Samir Amin, Pioneer of the Southern Renaissance,” 2014, Springer (  foreword by Dieter Singas ).

·                     The Law of Globalized Value,” 2012, translated by Saad Al-Tawil, National Center for Translation, Cairo ( introduction titled “Marx Without Borders ).

 

by: Samir Abu Zaid